Nov 19, 2007

Rising oil price equals rising profits, right? Wrong (The Economist, Nov 8th, 2007)

AS THE oil price climbed towards $100 a barrel during the past few weeks, big Western oil firms were reporting their results for the third quarter. Record oil prices, it turns out, do not translate into record profits. Oil is now close to exceeding the record set in 1979 of between $100 and $110, depending on how you adjust for inflation and what benchmark you use. Yet almost without exception, big oil firms' profits are falling from the peaks reached last year.

Exxon Mobil, for example, reported a 10% drop in profits in the third quarter, and BP's fell even more sharply. Profits also fell at Chevron, ConocoPhillips and Eni. They rose at Total and Royal Dutch Shell—but only thanks to exchange-rate fluctuations and one-off asset sales. Analysts at Citigroup calculate that, measured in dollars, the biggest oil firms' earnings fell by 15% on average.

To be fair, the oil price has surged most dramatically since the end of September, although it was also buoyant in the third quarter. The majors' poor showing also reflects lower profits from refining, as the difference in price between petrol and crude oil has fallen from the exceptionally high levels of recent months.

But the fact remains that oil giants are struggling to pump more oil and gas. In part, this is due to a quirk of the rules that oblige Western oil firms to share the crude they produce with state-owned oil firms in many countries. The contracts in question often stipulate that as the price goes up, the volume of oil the foreigners receive decreases. Worse, several countries are changing contracts or tax rules in ways that will further erode the Western oil firms' profits—and in some cases are throwing them out altogether.

Rising costs are also a problem. Exxon, which is known for its stringent financial discipline, saw costs rise almost twice as fast as revenue in the third quarter. The shortage of labour and equipment that is feeding this inflation is also causing delays to new projects. And there are not enough new projects in the pipeline. The International Energy Agency, an energy watchdog for rich countries, reckons that the expansion plans of the big Western and state-owned oil firms will leave the world 12.5m barrels per day short of requirements in 2015.

Despite this looming deficit and the glaring price signal, all the big companies except Total produced less oil and gas in the third quarter than they did in the same period last year. According to Citigroup, the average decline in overall output was 3.3%. If the relatively steady supply of natural gas is stripped out, the numbers look even worse: oil production fell by 9% on average. No matter how high the price goes, the oil majors cannot make a profit from oil they do not produce.

Nov 14, 2007

Оросын хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнийн өсөлт, үнийг барьж тогтоох нь

10 дугаар сарын сүүлээр ОХУ-ын Засгийн газар өргөн хэрэглээний хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүнийхээ үнийг шууд тогтоох арга хэмжээ авсан. Энэ хугацаанд ОХУ-ын ерөнхийлөгч Владимир Путины сонгуулийн компанит ажил явагдаж байгаа. Хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнийн огцом өсөлт нь Путины нэр хүндэд сөргөөр нөлөөлөх бөгөөд ялангуяа тэтгэврийн хөгшчүүдэд илүү хүндээр тусах болно.

Үүнтэй холбогдуулан Оросын засгийн газар томоохон жижиглэнгийн худалдаачид болон хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүн үйлдвэрлэгчидтэй сайн дурын гэрээ байгуулсан байна. Сайн дурын гэрээ нь эдгээр худалдаачид засгийн газрын тавьсан саналаас татгалзсан тохиолдолд татварын байцаан шалгалт, торгууль ноогдуулах, бизнесээ алдах зэрэг эрсдэлд орж болзошгүй тул тэд бүгд энэхүү гэрээг хүлээн зөвшөөрчээ. Гол нэрийн хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнийг 2008 оны 1 дүгээр сарын 31-ний өдрийг хүртэл буюу Думын сонгуулийн хугацаанд энэхүү тогтоосон түвшинд барихаар болжээ.

Хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнийг ингэж тогтоосноор Оросын эдийн засагт хүчтэй сөрөг нөлөөг үзүүлэхгүй байж болно. Үнийн өсөлт энэ жилийн төлөвлөж байсан 8 хувиас ийнхүү давсан нь Орос улсаас нөлөөлж чадахгүй гадны хүчин зүйлсээс шалтгаалжээ. Москва дахь Goldman Sachs-ын гүйцэтгэх захирал Rory MacFarquhar-ын хэлснээр зах зээл дээр үнийг тогтоон барих нь хомсдолд хүргэж, хар захын үйл ажиллагааг өөгшүүлэх зэргээр ямар их сөрөг үр дагавар авчрахыг Путин сайн мэдэж байх учиртай. Тиймээс үнийг ийнхүү барьж байгаа нь засгийн газрын авч хэрэгжүүлж байгаа бодлого болон үр дүнгийн талаар сонгогчдод тааламжтай сэтгэгдэл төрүүлэх гэсэн зорилготой гэж тэрээр хэлжээ.

Саяхан явуулсан санал асуулгаар Оросын хүн амын бараг тэн хагас нь хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнэ ийнхүү өсч байгаа нь үйлдвэрлэгчид болон худалдаачдын хоорондын хуйвалдаантай холбоотой гэж үзжээ. Ард түмний зовлонгоор ашиг олж байгаа эдгээр худалдаачдыг цаашид шийтгэж магадгүй болоод байна.

Оросын засгийн газраас үнийг ийнхүү тогтоон барих зэргээр авч хэрэгжүүлж байгаа арга барил нь хөдөө аж ахуй болон банкны системийн зэрэг Оросын эдийн засгийн бүтцийн олон асуудлыг шийдвэрлэхэд сайн нөлөө үзүүлэхгүй гэж Путины зөвлөх байснаа одоогоор Путиныг хурцаар шүүмжлэх болсон Андрей Иларионов үзэж байна.

Эх сурвалж:

2007 оны 11-р сарын 9-ний өдрийн

Өдрийн сонин

Хятадад хэрэглээний үнэ огцом өсч байна. Инфляци нь Хятадын дараагийн чухал экспорт болох уу?

Бээжин хотын оршин суугч 62 настай, тэтгэвэрийнхээ орлогоор амьдардаг Сү Яцинг-тэй Wallmart-ийн ажилтан уулзаж ярилцсан байна. Сү болон түүний нөхөр сарын 263 ам.долларын тэтгэврийн мөнгө авдаг бөгөөд сүүлийн үед тэдний тэтгэврийн мөнгө амьдралд нь хүрэлцэхгүй болжээ. Сү-гийн хүнсэндээ хэрэглэдэг самрын тосны үнэ сүүлийн хэдэн сард 2 дахин үнэтэй болж бусад гол нэрийн бүтээгдэхүүний өртөг мөн нэмэгдэж байгаа зэргээс шалтгаалан тэд сүү хэрэглэхээ больж махыг буурцагаар орлуулан хэрэглэх болжээ. Тэд өлсөөгүй ч гэсэн үнэ ингэж хурдацтай өсч байгаа нь тэднийг айлгаж байгаа талаар Сү гомдоллосон байна. Сү-тэй адил Хятадын олон ард түмний амьдралд учирч байгаа энэхүү асуудал нь удахгүй дэлхийн бусад улс оронд ч өргөн тархаж ялангуяа Барууны Wallmart мэтийн том хэмжээний жижиглэнгийн худалдааныханд илүү хүндээр тусч болох юм. Учир нь гэвэл Хятадын үйлдвэрүүдээс хямд үнээр үйлдвэрлэгдэн гарч байгаа экспортын бараанууд, тухайлбал 15 ам.долларын үнэтэй ноосон цамц, 25 ам.долларын үнэтэй пүүз, 100 ам.долларын үнэтэй DVD тоглуулагч зэрэг нь эх газрын Хятад улс өөрийн эдийн засгаа тогтоон барихаар тэмцэж байх энэ хооронд эдгээр бараануудын үнэ нэмэгдэж эхлэх магадлалтай байна. Энэхүү өсөлт нь зайлшгүй бий болно гэдэгтэй бүх эрдэмтэд санал нэг биш байгаа боловч зарим эрдэмтдийн сэрэмжлүүлж байгаагаар Хятадын өртөг багатай үйлдвэрлэл нь дэлхий дахинд үйлдвэрлэж буй бараа бүтээгдэхүүний үнийн ер бусын тогтвортой байдалд хүргэхэд туслаж байсан эрин үеийн төгсгөл ирж байна гэжээ. Америкийн Төв банкны хуучин ерөнхийлөгч Alan Greenspan өөрийн бичсэн ном болон сонинд өгсөн ярилцлагандаа Хятадын экспортын барааны үнэ өсч байгаа нь дэлхийн инфляцид нөлөөлөх болно гэсэн байна. Ben Simpfendorfer, Royal Bank of Scotland, хэлэхдээ: “Сүүлийн арван жилд Хятад улс дифляцийн нөлөө үзүүлдэг байсан бол ирэх арван жилд эсрэгээрээ инфляцийн нөлөө үзүүлэх болно” гэжээ.

Одоохондоо Хятадын Wallmart-ийн хувьд энэхүү нөхцөл байдал сайн мэдэгдэхгүй байж болох ч үнийн өсөлт нь бодит зүйл болоод байна. Хятадын болон бусад хурдацтай хөгжиж байгаа улс орнуудын эрэлт хэрэгцээний улмаас газрын тос болон бусад төрөл бүрийн барааны үнэ сүүлийн хэдэн жилд эрс нэмэгдэж байна. Тэгэхдээ эдийн засагчдын санааг зовоож байгаа гол асуудал нь Хятадад гэнэт бий болсон үнийн харьцангуй өндөр өсөлт болон түүний гадны улс орнуудад нөлөөлөх явдал болоод байна. Энэ жил Хятадын Төв банкнаас хүүгээ таван удаа өсгөсөн хэдий ч хэрэглээний үнийн индекс нэмэгдсээр л байна. 8 дугаар сард жилийн инфляцийн түвшин сүүлийн 10 жилд гараагүйгээр хурдан өсч 6.5 хувьд хүрчээ.

Засгийн газар болон зарим эдийн засагчид энэхүү огцом өсөлтийг 2006 оны дунд үеээс мах болон шувуун бүтээгдэхүүний үнэ 49 хувиар гэнэт өссөнтэй шууд холбон тайлбарлаж байна. Хятадын хэрэглээний сагсны гуравны нэгээс дээш хувийг эзэлдэг хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнэ нэмэгдсэн нь мал сүргийн тэжээлийн зардал өссөн болон малын өвчин гарсны улмаас 70 мянган гахай үхсэн зэрэгтэй холбоотой. 9 дүгээр сарын дундуур үнийг тогтвортой барихын тулд улсын нөөцөөс 30 мянган тонн гахайн махыг яаралтай бэлтгэн нийлүүлжээ.

Үүний зэрэгцээ бусад үнэ ч өссөөр байна. UBS-ын эдийн засагч Jonathan Anderson-ны үзэж байгаагаар Хятадад үл хөдлөх хөрөнгийн үнэ ойролцоогоор жилийн 10 хувиар нэмэгдсэн. 8 дугаар сарын инфляцийн дараагаар Хятадын засгийн газар улсын хяналтанд байдаг шатахуун, ус, цахилгаан зэргийн үнийг өсгөхгүй байх арга хэмжээ авчээ. Өндөр инфляци нь нийгмийн бухимдлыг нэмэгдүүлэхийг мэдэж байсан Засгийн газар аж ахуйн нэгж бизнес эрхлэгчдийг хэрэглэгчдийг хохироохоос урьдчилан сэргийлэх үүднээс тэдэнд сануулга өгсөн байна. Жишээ нь 8 дугаар сард бэлэн гоймонгийн үйлдвэрүүд хоорондоо хууль бусаар хуйвалдан үнээ өсгөсөн хэргээр Засгийн газраас тэднийг шийтгэжээ. Мөн үүний зэрэгцээгээр Бээжингийн эрх баригчид мужуудын засгийг цалингийн доод түвшний хэмжээг нэмэгдүүлэхийг шаардаж байна. Үүнд Бээжин, Шанхай, Шеньжэн, Гуанжоу болон Наньжин зэрэг хотууд цалингийн доод хэмжээг нэмэгдүүлжээ.

Дээрхи арга хэмжээ нь дэлхийн инфляцийн түвшин нэмэгдэхэд хүргэж болох юм. Хямд ажиллах хүчний улмаас л Хятад улс дэлхийн үйлдвэрлэлийн орон болж чадсан. Хятадын үйлдвэрлэлийн ажиллах нэг хүчний өртөг АНУ-ын үйлдвэрийн ажилчны цалингийн 4 хувьтай тэнцдэг гэсэн тооцоо байдаг. Харин одоо Хятадын эдийн засаг хүчирхэгжиж ДНБ-ний өсөлт 2 дугаар улиралд 11.9 хувьд хүрч, хот газрын ажилчдын бодит цалин хоёр оронгийн хувиар нэмэгдэж эхлэн, Засгийн газрын мэдээлж байгаагаар энэ оны эхний хагас жилд л гэхэд 18 хувиар өссөн байна. Мөн түүхий эд материалын үнэ нэмэгдэж байгаагаас үйлдвэрлэлийн зардал өсч байна. Үйлдвэрлэгчид энэ зардлыг хэрэглэгчдэд шууд дамжуулах бөгөөд Хятадын юанийн ханш чангарахад дээрх асуудал улам хүндрэлтэй болно. “Олон улсын хэмжээнд авч үзвэл Хятадаас авах импортын барааны үнэ нэмэгдэх болно” гэж BNP Paribas securities-ын эдийн засагч Чен Синдун хэлэв. Энэ 5 дугаар сард Хятадаас импортоор авсан барааны үнэ жилийн 0.1 хувиар нэмэгдэж байгааг бүртгэжээ. АНУ-ын Хөдөлмөрийн Яам 2005 оноос хойш Хятадын импортын үнийг судалж эхэлсэн бөгөөд тэр үеэс хойш үнэ сар бүр дор хаяж 0.3 хувиар нэмэгджээ.

Хэрвээ ийм маягаар үргэлжилвэл дэлхийн бусад улс орны төв банкуудад тэр дундаа АНУ-ын төв банкны ерөнхийлөгч Ben Bernanke-гийн хувьд асуудал бүр ч хүндрэлтэй болж ирэхээр байна. АНУ-ын сүүлийн үеийн эдийн засгийн байдлаас (ипотекийн хямрал) шалтгаалан Bernanke-ийн хүүгээ бууруулах гэж оролдож байгаа нь өндөр инфляцид хүргэж болохын хажуугаар АНУ-ын худалдааны хамгийн том түнш болох Хятадын инфляцийн асуудал нь түүний хүүгээ цаашид бууруулахад нь сөрөг нөлөө үзүүлнэ. Bernanke Бээжингийн эрх баригчдаас тусламж авч чадахгүй л болов уу. Хятадын тал өөрийн гэсэн үзэл баримтлалтай, мөн хэрэглээний үнийн талаар авч хэрэгжүүлж чадах хэрэгсэл нь хязгаарлагдмал. Өөрийн валютын хөрвөх чадварыг бууруулах замаар эдийн засгийн өсөлтөө бууруулж байгаа Хятадын тал эргэлтэнд байгаа мөнгөний хэмжээг бууруулахын тулд Хятадын арилжааны банкуудаас төв банкиндаа нөөц хэлбэрээр хадгалах мөнгөний хэмжээг нь энэ жилд гэхэд л 7 удаа нэмсэн боловч төдийлөн сайн үр дүнд хүрээгүй байна.

Хятадын төв банкны ерөнхийлөгч Жоу Шиаочуан-д тулгарч байгаа хүндрэлтэй асуудал нь Хятад улс нь эдийн засгийн төсөөлөл болон бодлого боловсруулах бодит, чанартай статистик дутагдалтай байгаатай холбоотой. Үүнээс гадна, мөнгөний болон сангийн бодлого нь улс төртэй нягт холбоотой байдаг. Хятадын ерөнхийлөгч Ху Жинтао-гийн цалинг нэмэгдүүлэн ядуу ажилчдыг эмнэлгийн үйлчилгээнд хамруулах зэргээр улсаас иргэдэд үзүүлэх үйлчилгээг сайжруулах төсөл нь ард түмэнд сайнаар хүрч байгаа боловч инфляцийг нэмэгдүүлж болох юм. Цалин багатай ажилчдын цалингийн хэмжээ нэмэгдэхэд тэдний хэрэглээ нэмэгдэж илүү их мөнгө зарцуулах хандлагатай болж энэ нь инфляцийн асуудал болж хувирна гэж Ben Simpfendorfer хэлжээ. Дэлхийн банкны ахлах эдийн засагч байсан Albert Keidel хэлэхдээ: “Улс төрийн болгоомжлолоос болж эрх баригчид цаг тухайд нь гэнэтийн шаардлагатай арга хэмжээ авч чадахгүй байна” гэсэн байна.

Эдийн засгийн хурдацтай өсөлт нь инфляцийн өндөр түвшинд хүргэдэг болохыг Хятадын эрх баригчид ойлгож эхэлсэн. Хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнэ нэмэгдэж байгаа нь эрх баригчдийн зовоож байна. Хятад хүмүүс мөнгө их олж баяжих тусам мах их иддэг. Гахайн махны нийлүүлэлт нэмэгдээд ирэхээр энэ жилийн сүүлээр хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүний үнэ тогтворжоод ирэх байх гэсэн хэдий ч бэлчээрийн нутаг ховордож байгаа болон усны нөөцийн асуудал хэвээр байх болно гэж Хонг Конг-ийн JP Morgan-ны мэргэжилтэн хэлж байна.

Хятадын дэлхий даяарх экспорт нь зайлшгүй инфляцид хүргэнэ гэдэгтэй зарим эдийн засагчид санаа нийлэхгүй байна. Citibank-ны эдийн засагч Yiping Huang-ны хийсэн судалгааны ажилд, Хятадад цалин нэмэгдэхийн зэрэгцээ ажиллах хүчний ажлын чадавхи илүү сайжирч байгаагаас үйлдвэрлэгчид үнээ нэмэх шаардлагагүй хэмээжээ. Эдийн засагч Gerard Lyons-ын үзэж байгаагаар Хятад улс автомашин зэргийн илүү их үнэтэй бүтээгдэхүүн үйлдвэрлэж эхэлсэн нь хэдэн жилийн дараа мөн дифляцийн нөлөө үзүүлэх болно гэжээ.

Сү болон түүний нөхөр өдөр тутмын хэрэглээний хүнснийхээ талаар санаа нь зовсон хэвээр л байна. Хэрвээ хувцас үнэтэй болох юм бол бид хуучин хувцсаа өмсчихнө, харин хоол хүнсний хувьд үнэ нь хичнээн өсч байсан ч гэсэн хоол идэх л болно гэж тэд хэлж байна.
Эх сурвалж:
2007 оны 10-р сарын 26-ны
Өдрийн сонин
Зууны мэдээ

Chairman Ben S. Bernanke: Federal Reserve Communications

At the Cato Institute 25th Annual Monetary Conference, Washington, D.C. November 14, 207

The more fully the public understands what the function of the Federal Reserve System is, and on what grounds its policies and actions are based, the simpler and easier will be the problems of credit administration in the U.S.
– Federal Reserve Board, Annual Report, 1923, p. 95.

Montagu Norman, the Governor of the Bank of England from 1921 to 1944, reputedly took as his personal motto, "Never explain, never excuse." Norman's aphorism exemplified how he and many of his contemporaries viewed the making of monetary policy--as an arcane and esoteric art, best practiced out of public view. Many central bankers of Norman's time (and, indeed, well into the postwar period) believed that a certain mystique attached to their activities and that allowing the public a glimpse of the inner workings would only usurp the prerogatives of insiders and reduce, if not grievously damage, the effectiveness of policy.

Norman's perspective on central banking now seems decidedly quaint. Over the past few decades, central banks around the world have worked assiduously to become more open about their activities. In fact, Norman's own institution, the Bank of England, has in recent years been a leading exponent of increased transparency in central banking. Monetary policy makers have adopted a range of methods to improve their communication with the public, including timely announcements of policy actions, expanded testimony before members of the legislature, the release of minutes of policy meetings, frequent public speeches, and the regular publication of reports about the economy and monetary policy. This increased openness is a welcome development for several reasons. Most importantly, monetary policy makers are public servants whose decisions affect the life of every citizen; consequently, in a democratic society, they have a responsibility to give the people and their elected representatives a full and compelling rationale for the decisions they make. Good communications are a prerequisite if central banks are to maintain the democratic legitimacy and independence that are essential to sound monetary policy making.

In addition, a considerable amount of evidence indicates that central bank transparency increases the effectiveness of monetary policy and enhances economic and financial performance in several ways. First, improving the public's understanding of the central bank's objectives and policy strategies reduces economic and financial uncertainty and thereby allows businesses and households to make more-informed decisions. Second, if practitioners in financial markets gain a better understanding of how policy is likely to respond to incoming information, asset prices and bond yields will tend to respond to economic data in ways that further the central bank's policy objectives. For example, if market participants understand that arriving information about the economy increases the likelihood of certain policy actions, then market interest rates will tend to move in a way that reinforces the expected actions, effectively supporting the goals of the central bank. Third, clarity about the central bank's policy objectives and strategy may help anchor the public's long-term inflation expectations, which can substantially improve the efficacy of policy and the overall functioning of the economy. Finally, open discussion of the central bank's analyses and forecasts invites valuable input and feedback from the public.

The benefits of an open and accountable policymaking process have spurred the Federal Reserve, along with other major central banks, to take a number of actions over the years to increase its transparency. Appropriately, given the unique position of the Federal Reserve and the sensitivity of financial markets to its communications, these steps have generally been incremental in nature; but, taken together, they have substantially increased the ability of the American public to understand and to anticipate monetary policy decisions.

The Congress has also long been aware of the importance of Federal Reserve transparency and accountability; in particular, a series of resolutions and laws passed in the 1970s set clear policy objectives for the Federal Reserve and required it to provide regular reports and testimony to the Congress.1 Since 1975, the Federal Reserve has presented testimony twice each year to the Congress on the conduct of monetary policy. These semiannual presentations have become an important vehicle for the U.S. central bank to make known its views on the outlook and on the appropriate stance of policy. Other notable milestones in the Federal Reserve's progress toward greater openness include: in 1979, the first release of semiannual economic projections; in 1983, the first publication of the Beige Book, which summarizes information about economic conditions received from the Federal Reserve System's business contacts; in 1994, the decision to release a postmeeting statement when policy actions had been taken; in 2000, the beginning of the practice of issuing a statement after each meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) and including in the statement an assessment of the balance of risks to the Committee's objectives; in 2002, adding the FOMC roll call vote to the postmeeting statement; and in 2005, the speeding up of the release of the minutes of FOMC meetings, from a delay of some six or seven weeks to just three weeks.

In testimony to the Congress at the time of my nomination as Chairman, in 2005, I pledged to continue the trend toward greater openness sustained under Chairman Greenspan. In so doing, I stressed the importance of continuity with the policies and strategies that have served the American economy well. Any further changes, I promised, would come only pursuant to a consensus within the FOMC that those changes would enhance the Committee's ability to pursue its dual mandate of achieving maximum employment and price stability.

Toward that end, the FOMC has engaged in extensive deliberations over the past year or so to consider further steps toward greater transparency. Guided by a subcommittee chaired by Board Vice Chairman Donald Kohn, the FOMC reviewed the full range of our communications with the public.2 As indicated in a statement issued by the FOMC today, these discussions have led to a decision to increase the frequency and expand the content of the publicly released economic projections that are made by Federal Reserve Board members and Reserve Bank presidents. As I mentioned, the Federal Reserve has published economic projections for almost thirty years, and, indeed, the Federal Reserve was the first major central bank to release such projections.3 Today's announcement builds on that foundation. In the remainder of my remarks I will describe the changes that we plan to make, and then explain why I believe that, collectively, they represent an important further step toward greater transparency.

Toward More Informative Economic Projections
Because monetary policy affects spending and inflation with a lag, policy decisions must be based on an assessment of medium-term economic prospects. Thus, the Committee cannot fully explain its policy decisions without sharing its economic outlook with the public and the Congress. To provide more-timely information about the evolving outlook, the Federal Reserve will release FOMC participants' economic projections four times each year, rather than twice each year as we have done previously.

Projections will continue to be released in February and July of each year to coincide with the semiannual Monetary Policy Report and the associated testimony to the Congress. Two additional sets of projections will be published in conjunction with the minutes of the FOMC meetings held around the beginnings of the second quarter and the fourth quarter of the year (in 2008, the April and October meetings). The first expanded set of projections will be released next week, on November 20, together with the minutes of the October FOMC meeting. The horizon of the projections will be extended from two years to three. The projections released next week will extend through 2010.4

Each of the participants in the FOMC meeting--including the Federal Reserve Board members and all the Reserve Bank presidents--will, as in the past, provide projections for the growth of real gross domestic product (GDP), the unemployment rate, and core inflation (that is, inflation excluding the prices of food and energy items). In addition, participants will now provide their projections for overall inflation. Both overall and core inflation will continue to be based on the price index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE).5

Projections will continue to be made independently by each FOMC participant under the assumption of "appropriate" monetary policy, that is, the future evolution of the federal funds rate judged by that participant to be the one most likely to foster economic outcomes that satisfy the Federal Reserve's dual mandate. Following past practice, we will publish the central tendency and the range of the projections for each variable and each year.6 We will also publish a comparison with the previous set of quarterly projections; a chart showing central tendencies and ranges for each variable; and charts showing the distribution of participants' projections and how that distribution has changed since the previous release.

Accompanying the numerical projections will be a discussion--a projections "narrative" if you will--that summarizes participants' views of the major forces shaping the outlook, discusses the sources of risk to that outlook, and describes the dispersion of views among policymakers. By providing a medium-term perspective, the narrative will complement the discussion of shorter-term developments contained in the minutes. We will also provide qualitative information about participants' views on both the uncertainty and the balance of risks surrounding the outlook, together with quantitative historical information on the typical range of projection errors.7 Of course, the specific material provided and its form of presentation may change over time as we gain experience and receive feedback.

Benefits of the Enhanced Projections
The enhanced projections will provide the public with several types of useful information. In particular, I find it helpful to think of the projections as functioning in three different ways: as a forecast, as a provisional plan, and as an evaluation of certain long-run features of the economy.

Most obviously, the projections reflect the economic forecasts of FOMC participants and as such should provide the public with greater and more-timely insight into the Committee's views of the economic outlook and the risks to that outlook. Of course, because our knowledge of the structure of the economy is incomplete and future economic disturbances are often unforeseeable, economic forecasting is a highly uncertain enterprise.8 The only economic forecast in which I have complete confidence is that the economy will not evolve along the precise path implied by our projections. Nevertheless, as I have already noted, because policy affects spending and inflation with a lag, Committee members have no choice other than to make medium-term forecasts--provisional and subject to uncertainty though they may be. Providing more information about these forecasts, including discussions of the factors underlying the forecasts and of FOMC participants' assessments of the risks to the Committee's objectives, should improve the public's understanding of the rationale for the current stance of monetary policy and any changes to that stance. The public will also be better able to judge the extent to which the Committee's rationale is reasonable and persuasive.

The projections also function as a plan for policy--albeit as a rough and highly provisional one. As I mentioned earlier, FOMC participants will continue to base their projections on the assumption of "appropriate" monetary policy. Consequently, the extended projections will provide a sense of the economic trajectory that Committee participants see as best fulfilling the Federal Reserve's dual mandate, given the initial conditions and the constraints posed by the structure of the economy. To illustrate, consider the question of the length of time over which a central bank should aim to restore price stability following an unwanted increase in inflation. A central bank that places weight on both employment and price stability, like the Federal Reserve, would not attempt to disinflate immediately or establish a fixed time frame for the restoration of price stability. Rather, the optimal expected time required for completing the disinflation would depend on a host of factors, including the size of the initial deviation from price stability, the initial state of the real economy (for example, the level of unemployment), whether the rise in inflation resulted from transitory or more persistent sources, the extent to which inflation expectations are well anchored, and so on. In circumstances in which disinflationary policy is necessary, the extended economic projections would make clear that the Federal Reserve is committed to maintaining price stability, but they would also provide some indications about what the Committee views as the most appropriate pace of disinflation, given the state of the economy and the requirements of the dual mandate. In like fashion, the speed at which policy aims to return the economy to its sustainable rates of growth and employment following a period of resource slack should depend in part on the nature and extent of inflation risks, among other considerations. More generally, the extended projections will convey additional information about the Committee's policy strategies and thus help augment the Committee's transparency, predictability, and accountability.

Finally, the extended projections will embody information about FOMC participants' evaluations of certain long-run features of the economy, evaluations determined both by the economy's structure and by the Committee's policy objectives. Because of the extension of the projection horizon to three years, participants' inflation projections will convey more information regarding their views about the measured rate of inflation that, in the long run, is consistent with the Committee's dual objectives of maximum employment and price stability. Were price stability the only objective mandated for the Federal Reserve, the FOMC presumably would strive to achieve zero inflation, properly measured--that is, the optimal measured inflation rate would deviate from zero on average only by the amount of the estimated measurement error in the preferred inflation index. But under the Federal Reserve's dual mandate, the determination of the appropriate long-run inflation rate must take account of factors that may affect the efficient functioning of the economy at very low rates of inflation, such as the risk that the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates might hinder the effectiveness of monetary policy. Thus, the (properly measured) long-run inflation rate that best promotes the dual mandate is likely to be low but not zero.

Ultimately, households and businesses care about the overall, or "headline," rate of inflation; therefore, the FOMC should refer to an overall inflation rate when evaluating whether the Committee has met its mandated objectives over the long run. For that reason, the Committee has decided to publish projections for overall inflation as well as core inflation. In its policy statements and elsewhere, the Committee makes frequent reference to core inflation because, in light of the volatility of food and energy prices, core inflation can be a useful short-run indicator of the underlying trend in inflation. However, at longer horizons, where monetary policy has the greatest control over inflation, the overall inflation rate is the appropriate gauge of whether inflation is at a rate consistent with the dual mandate.

FOMC participants will continue to couch their inflation projections in terms of PCE inflation, rather than, say, inflation as measured by the consumer price index, because the PCE index is generally thought to provide the single most comprehensive and theoretically compelling measure of consumer prices. That said, no single measure of inflation is perfect, and the Committee will continue to monitor a range of measures when forming its view about inflation prospects.

The lengthening of the projection horizon will also allow the public to infer more about FOMC participants' current judgments about the rate of GDP growth and the unemployment rate that the economy can sustain in the long run. Over time, effective monetary policies foster rates of growth and unemployment close to their long-run sustainable rates. However, in contrast to inflation, which in the long run is determined by monetary policy, the rates of economic growth and unemployment that can be sustained in the long run are determined by many factors outside the control of central banks. Among these factors are the advance of technology, entrepreneurial activities, the growth in the size of the labor force, the rate at which workers acquire new skills, tax and regulatory policies, and the efficiency of labor markets in matching workers with positions. Consequently, the long-run sustainable rates of economic growth and unemployment should be viewed as constraints on what monetary policy can achieve and not as variables that policymakers can freely choose. In addition, estimates of sustainable rates of growth and unemployment have been shown to be highly uncertain at any point in time; and they may vary significantly over time in light of new information and changes in the structure of the economy. Thus, the longer-run projections of growth and unemployment should be treated with considerable caution.

Relationship to Inflation Targeting
As you may know, I have been an advocate of the monetary policy strategy known as inflation targeting, used in many countries around the world. Inflation targeting is characterized by two features: an explicit numerical target or target range for inflation and a high degree of transparency about forecasts and policy plans. The steps being taken by the Federal Reserve, I must emphasize, are intended only to improve our communication with the public; the conduct of policy itself will not change. Nonetheless, in light of the changes to communications we are undertaking, one might fairly ask how the Federal Reserve's approach relates to inflation targeting.

A superficial drawback of inflation targeting is its very name, which suggests a single-minded focus on inflation to the exclusion of other goals. In fact, the practice of monetary policy in an inflation-targeting regime is not necessarily inconsistent with a dual mandate such as that given to the Federal Reserve; indeed, most if not all inflation-targeting central banks today practice "flexible" inflation targeting, meaning that they take account of other economic goals besides price stability--notably economic growth, employment, and financial stability--when making policy decisions. Moreover, a broad consensus exists among central banks, whether they have an explicit numerical target for inflation or not, that maintaining low and stable inflation over time is the best means by which monetary policy can promote economic efficiency and maximize the nation's economic welfare. Thus, at least since the stabilization of U.S. inflation in the 1980s, the Federal Reserve's approach to monetary policy has had much in common with that of central banks that describe themselves as inflation targeters.

Nevertheless, some aspects of inflation targeting may be less well suited to the Federal Reserve's mandate and policy practice. In particular, although inflation-targeting central banks certainly pay attention to economic growth and employment, their formal accountability is often largely couched only in terms of a price-stability objective. Likewise, the communication strategies of inflation-targeting central banks tend to be focused on the formal inflation objective and the horizon over which that objective will be achieved. As I have emphasized today, the Federal Reserve is legally accountable to the Congress for two objectives, maximum employment and price stability, on an equal footing. My colleagues and I strongly support the dual mandate and the equal weighting of objectives that it implies. Of course, as I have discussed, the Federal Reserve's influence over these objectives differs importantly in the long run: Monetary policy determines the long-run inflation rate, whereas the factors that influence the sustainable rates of growth and employment in the long run are largely outside the central bank's control. Still, over time, monetary policy must strive to foster rates of growth and employment close to their long-run sustainable rates. The Federal Reserve must thus be accountable for the effects of its policies on the real economy as well as on inflation. The enhanced projections that I have described today will provide additional information pertinent to both halves of the Federal Reserve's mandate.

At a more technical level, the Federal Reserve differs from most inflation-targeting central banks in that it provides information about the independent projections of Committee members rather than a single collective forecast. To some extent, that difference reflects the relatively large size of the FOMC and the geographic dispersion of Committee participants; those factors would make the development of a detailed consensus forecast quite difficult as a practical matter. But, as I will discuss briefly, such a diversity of viewpoints can enhance the quality of policy decisions.

The Diversity of the Committee
An important strength of the Federal Open Market Committee is its diversity. The Board members and Reserve Bank presidents who sit around the table at each meeting of the FOMC bring a wide range of perspectives to the deliberations that reflect the participants' professional backgrounds, the regions of the country with which they are most familiar, and their differing approaches to economic and policy analysis. The task participants face at each meeting is to forge a rough consensus regarding the outlook, the risks to the Committee's objectives, and the appropriate policy response. Of course, it is not always possible--indeed, it would be rather unusual--to come to a set of conclusions that fully represent the views of every participant. But the process of searching for common ground is itself an important aspect of how the Committee operates. Diversity of views drives the Committee to adopt an eclectic approach and thus serves to limit the risk that a single viewpoint or analytical framework might become unduly dominant.

The changes to the projections process announced today preserve the important role played by this diversity of perspectives. As I have noted, Committee participants will continue to produce individual projections that reflect their judgments about the state of the economy and their approaches to policy. From the internal perspective, I expect the more frequent sharing of projections and the additional information they contain will improve our discussions and policy debates. From the external perspective, the public will gain additional and more frequent information about both the central tendencies and diversity of participants' views. In particular, the additional narrative material that will accompany the numerical projections will illuminate both the consensus of opinion and the differences in judgments that may emerge.

Conclusion
The communications strategy of the Federal Reserve is a work in progress. I believe that the changes announced by the FOMC today are an important advance: The changes will provide a more-timely insight into the Committee's outlook, will help households and businesses better understand and anticipate how our policy decisions respond to incoming information, and will enhance our accountability for the decisions we make. But the changes are also evolutionary, in that they build on long-established practices; in that respect, they represent just one more step on the road toward greater transparency at the Federal Reserve. The Committee will continue to look for ways to improve the accountability and public understanding of U.S. monetary policy making.

Source: http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20071114a.htm

Хойтон ам.долларын ханш сулрах магадлалтай

Нийгмийн толь Бямба, 2007 оны 11-р сарын 10

Төсвийн төсөлд тусгаснаар ирэх онд дотоодын нийт бүтээгдэхүүний өсөлт 10.1 хувьтай байх нь. Аж үйлдвэр тэр дундаа боловсруулах үйлдвэрийн салбарт хүнсний бүтээгдэхүүн үйлдвэрлэл, нэхмэл болон хувцас үйлдвэрлэлийн салбаруудад нэлээд өсөлт гаргахаар байгаа аж. Түүнчлэн ирэх оноос эхлэн "Оюу толгой" төслийн бэлтгэл ажлын хүрээнд дэд бүтэц барьж байгуулах ажил эхлэх юм байна. Түүнээс гадна бүтээн байгуулалтын томоохон төслүүд хэрэгжиж эхлэх бололтой. Мөн үйлдвэр технологийн парк байгуулах ажил ирэх оноос хийгдэхээр ирэх жилийн төсөлд тусгагдсан байна. Эдгээр бүтээн байгуулалтын ажлын үр дүнд үйлдвэрлэл, үйлчилгээ өсч, эдийн засгийн өсөлт нэмэгдэхээр байгаа бололтой. Улсын болон хувийн хөрөнгө оруулалт өсч, 40 мянган сууц хөтөлбөр хэрэгжиж байгаатай холбоотойгоор барилгын салбарын өсөлт харьцангуй хурдан байх нь. Өнгөрсөн жил татварын багц хуульд нэмэлт өөрчлөлт оруулсаны дүнд татварын ачаалал багасч бизнөсийн үйл ажиллагаа идэвхжиж, гадаадын хөрөнгө оруулалт нэмэгдсэн гэж үзэж байгаа аж.

Эцсийн хэрэглээний үнийн дүн ирэх онд бага зэрэг өсөхөөр байна
Шатах тослох материалын үнэ оны сүүлч болон ирэх онд нэмэгдэхээр байгаа аж. Дэлхийн зах зээл дээрх эрэлтээс шалтгаалан нефтийн үнэ буурахгүй байна. Тухайлбал, олон улсын энергийн агентлагаас гаргасан судалгаагаар дэлхийн нефтийн нэг өдрийн хэрэгцээ 88.2 сая баррелль буюу өнгөрсөн оны түвшингээс 2.56 хувиар өсөхөөр байна. Ирэх онд УИХ-ын ээлжит сонгууль болох, гадаад зах зээл дээр манай импортын зарим нэр төрлийн барааны үнэ өсөх хандлагатай уялдан ирэх жилийн эцэст хзрэглээний үнийн индекс бага зэрэг өсөх төлөвтэй байгаа бололтой. Ирэх жил инфляц нэг оронтой тоонд байхаар төсвийн төсөлд тусгажээ.

Экспортын хэмжээ дараа жил өснө
Эдийн засгийн өсөлт, томоохон төсөл хөтөлбөр хэрэгжиж уул уурхайн үйлдвэрлэлийн бүтээгдэхүүн нэмэгдэж буйтай холбогдуулан экспортын хэмжээ өсч, гадаад валютын нөөц сүүлийн жилүүдэд нэмэгдэн, ирэх онд төгрөгийн ам.доллартай харьцах ханш бага зэрэг сулрах хандлагатай байгаа аж. Мөн дараагийн хоёр жилд ч бага зэрэг буурах боломжтой бололтой. Ирэх онд дотоодын нийт бүтээгдэхүүнд эзлэх гадаад худалдааны тэнцлийн ашиг 0.7-3.9 байхаар байна.

Экспортын хэмжээг ирэх онд 21.9 хувь харин дараагийн хоёр жилд нь 14-22 хувь хүртэл өсгөхөөр тооцож байгаа бөгөөд гадаад худалдааны тэнцэл ирэх онд 35, 2009-2010 онд 304 сая ам.долларын ашигтай байхаар тооцжээ. Энэ нь дэлхийн зах зэзл дээр алт, зэсийн үнэ харьцангуй тогтвортой байх, "Оюу толгой"," Таван толгой" зэрэг уул уурхайн томоохон төсөл, хөтөлбөр хэрэгжиж эхлэхтэй холбогдон уул уурхайн бүтээгдэхүүн үйлдвэрлэлийн хэмжээ нэмэгдэхээс шалтгаалах юм байна.

Ж.Байгал